This paper draws from The Lathe of Heaven by Ursula Le Guin to highlight some of the most likely pitfalls on the political road to a sustainable planet. Through the literary device of dreams that can change the world, Le Guin explores how the individual’s egoistic desire to save humanity can be twisted by the limitations of our psyche and our society, turning an already uncomfortable future Earth into a devastated planet. It is a stinging critique of answers handed down from above, and a call to action for those of us who just get by here below. Her story warns of the ancient “road to hell”, paved and trodden by would be saviors with the best intentions but also points to the license that public apathy provides to the powerful when the costs of environmental harm are borne by the powerless. These disconnects, combined with cycles of rationalization, silver bullet mentalities, and the tendency to scapegoat others for negative side effects, can all derail sustainability transitions. Lathe provides an allegorical assessment of this process, but much more study is needed to fully understand and regulate the resulting governance treadmill.

Transitioning to a more sustainable world requires changes in technologies, economies, and societies. While a few of these changes may occur spontaneously, most experts agree that some level of policy intervention is necessary (Loorbach 2010; Frantzeskaki, Loorbach, and Meadowcroft 2012). Even in advanced democracies, policy making tends to be reactive, rather than proactive. That is, governments respond to the complaints of powerful constituencies, rather than working to prevent problems before they occur (Baumgartner and Jones 2009; Sabatier and Brasher 1993; Kingdon 2011; Webster 2015a; de Gooyert et al. 2016). Thus, we can expect more attention—and more action—on an environmental problem when related costs are felt by powerful interest groups or, in democracies, by a majority of the public. Although this responsiveness is problematic in itself, delaying policy making and increasing the risk of major environmental catastrophes, the political will created by environmental stresses can also be co-opted or channeled into unhelpful responses (Hendriks 2009). These pitfalls in the path to sustainability are dangerous and need to be avoided for a successful transition.

In this paper, I use The Lathe of Heaven by Ursula Le Guin (1976; reprint of 1971 edition) to explore a range of factors that prevent effective environmental governance and hinder the transition to sustainability, which requires political as well as socio-technological evolution (Frantzeskaki, Loorbach, and Meadowcroft 2012; Voß and Bornemann 2011). Le Guin is one of the few authors of science fiction who writes about transition itself, rather than building up a fictional future and leaving the source of transition to the imagination of the reader. Several of her books (e.g. The Phoenix, The Eye of the Heron) center on political transition via revolution but in Lathe she grapples with social and psychological aspects of transitions to a more peaceful and sustainable planet. Although politics are peripheral in this book, it remains an apt allegory for modern sustainability transitions.

Lathe features many of the deep social problems that we still fear—and even experience—today. Overpopulation, food shortages, global warming, polluted air and water, and war in the Middle East are just a few examples of the elements that give her dystopia an enduring depth. However, her story warns of a deeper concern, the ancient “road to hell”, paved and trodden by would be saviors with the best intentions. Each of the three main characters in the book, George Orr, William Haber, and Heather Lelache, represents a different category of political actor and the interactions between them parallel processes in modern environmental politics. Orr embodies the apathetic public, Haber epitomizes the well-intentioned but disconnected policy maker, and Lelache symbolizes the marginalized peoples who have little power but are heavily impacted both by environmental problems and by ill-conceived solutions. The construct of “effective dreams” provides both the dramatic tension and the power to transform the world—always at a cost.

This essay draws on Lathe to highlight two major political factors that hinder sustainability transitions. First, the power disconnect, which occurs whenever those who experience environmental harm are politically marginalized. This is similar to the fractured politics of transition depicted by Hendriks (2016) but includes minority and disenfranchised groups as well as the public. Second, cycles of rationalization widen power disconnects by allowing decision makers to take credit for positive policy outcomes while blaming others for negative impacts. The public may eventually be roused from its apathy to fight for the rights of the marginalized (as per the storyline in Lathe) but large portions of the public may also participate in cycles of rationalization, blaming the marginalized, political leaders, or others for problems that are caused by the whole of society.

As shown allegorically in Lathe, there are three related “minor” pitfalls that also plague disconnected systems and foster cycles of rationalization. First, decision makers tend to favor silver bullets or relatively simplistic solutions that are politically expedient. By their nature, these simple solutions do not solve problems, but instead postpone effective response. One way to dampen problem signals via silver bullets is to shift costs from elites to marginalized populations, creating negative side effects. There can be unintended consequences associated with any type of environmental regulation, but this second pitfall is most common in highly disconnected systems. Third, when ongoing problems and negative side-effects become too pressing to ignore, decision makers (and the public) can deny responsibility by blaming scapegoats. More than any other pitfall, attributing the costs of governance failures to scapegoats facilitates cycles of rationalization.

Because governance is reactive rather than proactive, these five factors tend to delay effective response to environmental governance and perpetuate grave injustices. As Webster (2015a) points out, when power disconnects are wide, governance tends to go through multiple cycles of ineffective response because full problem signals are not reaching decision makers. This effect is further amplified by cycles of rationalization, which reinforce the use of silver bullets by placing the blame for negative side effects on scapegoats. As long as the environmental problem is escalating, a system that is stuck in an ineffective cycle will eventually be driven to some crisis point, when it will either collapse or be forced to transition into a more effective cycle. In Lathe, this point occurs at the turning point near the end of the book, but real systems usually cycle back and forth between effective and ineffective cycles in a process called the governance treadmill.

This paper starts by parsing out the political allegory in Lathe as it relates to the major pitfalls described above: power disconnects and cycles of rationalization. Minor pitfalls are covered under the later because, while each causes problems in its own right, the feedback between silver bullets, side effects, and scapegoats is an important component in cycles of rationalization. The next section describes the governance treadmill and shows how it is depicted in Lathe. The third section delves into historical and modern events to demonstrate how the five pitfalls together affect the governance treadmill, both within Le Guin’s allegory and in the real world. The paper concludes with the need for further exploration of the governance treadmill and explicit inclusion of the five pitfalls in an interdisciplinary research program to study political-socio-technological transitions.

Written in 1971, Le Guin’s Lathe depicts a dystopian future in the best tradition of the genre. However, the genius of the book lies in the plot device of “effective dreams”, which allow the protagonist, George Orr, to change the world—past, present, and future—with little to no effort. When Orr is placed in psychiatric care, his councilor, William Haber, appropriates this power by using a device to control Orr’s dreams. This sets the stage for conflict between characters with very different personalities. Where Orr is connected, humble, and passive, Haber is distanced, arrogant, and aggressive. Orr fears the power in his dreams but Haber embraces it as a means to improve the imperfect world in which they both live. One would do nothing, the other everything. The imbalance between them is the difference between a Malthusian nightmare, which is caused by insufficient collective action, and an Orwellian nightmare, which results from the arrogant use of power by a disconnected individual or group.1 However, it is the character of Lelache who truly represents the dispossessed and who, with many unnamed actors, pays the highest price for Haber’s hubris and Orr’s inaction.

Power disconnects

This section describes how power disconnects are represented in Lathe. According to Webster (2015a), a power disconnect occurs when the people who feel the costs of environmental harm are unable to change environmental policy. When power disconnects are wide, political will tends to be low and policy responses favor the status quo, even if environmental damage is quite high. When disconnects are narrow, political will to solve environmental problems is high, and policies are more likely to be effective at reducing environmental harms, though costs may still be transferred to marginalized populations who might otherwise be more insulated from environmental damage (e.g. construction of a levee that protects a wealthy district while diverting floodwater closer to a poor community). This depiction of politics is somewhat different from the literature on sustainability transitions, which tends to focus on general representation/deliberation (Hendriks 2016; Ercan and Hendriks 2013) or on preventing consolidation of power by local elites (Voß and Bornemann 2011). Moreover, this perspective highlights the role of the dynamic incentives associated with environmental impacts as well as more static incentive structures such as economic advancement or a quest for political power. Such incentives are largely ignored in the transitions literature, which tends to be constructivist (governance is socially constructed), even though Giddens’ (1979) work on structuration, which recognizes the feedbacks between governance structures and human actions, is often cited.2

Each of the three main characters in Lathe represents an ideal type in their own right, but the conflict between them is essentially a story of power disconnects. On the one hand, the character George Orr has no ambition beyond leading a normal life. Pallid and thin, he is the epitome of average, content with his place in the world, even though, “undernourishment, overcrowding, and pervading foulness of the environment were the norm” (p. 31). Indeed, his effective dreams seem to be his only extraordinary aspect. These dreams do not change the future per se, but rather shift the world to a different “continuum” in which the past has changed to make a new present possible. Only Orr and those who are with him at the moment of change remember what previous version of the world existed before each effective dream. Until assigned to Haber for his “Voluntary Therapeutic Treatment (VTT)”, Orr only had effective dreams under conditions of severe stress. In these cases, the stressor was usually removed via the dream and, with so many stressors in his life, Orr was deeply anxious about the activities of his dreaming mind.

In spite of the squalor of the Malthusian dystopia he lives in, Orr would be happy to work, love, have a family, and lead a “simple” life. Heidegger and other philosophers refer to this as getting caught up in the “everyday” (Seckinelgin 2006; Heidegger 2010 [1953]). This political apathy allows interest groups to develop policy monopolies, controlling public resources and usurping political power (R. Hardin 1995). At the beginning of the book, the effects of this dynamic are reflected in the invasive nature of the government, which uses many methods to control the population in the face of severe shortages of food, housing, and other necessities. Rationing is required for almost everything, including recreational drugs, which are provided in limited amounts for free via tightly monitored “pharm cards”. There are also pseudo-cigarettes labeled “tranks”, “derricks”, and “transcaps” that are designed to keep people content with what little they have. At the extreme, there is even a story about a government program that experimented with induced agoraphobia to ensure that people would be happy in the crowded conditions of the city.

This focus on placating and controlling the population—keeping them happy even though their everyday is impoverished—is a major concern of the government because when that everyday life is threatened, the public can be mobilized to bring about political change (R. Hardin 1982; Jones and Baumgartner 2004; Hirschman 1993). In the story, we never see the public itself rise up but this dynamic is reflected in the behavior of Orr’s character. He is generally passive throughout most of the book. After the first round of changes instigated by Haber, Orr starts to avoid his “therapy” sessions and even goes so far as to engage a civil rights attorney (Lelache) to get away from Haber. Lelache is not able to stop the treatments, but she and Orr fall in love, which enriches Orr’s everyday considerably. With no legal recourse, Orr’s treatments continue, as do the negative effects of the dreams that Haber controls. Orr does not really fight back against Haber again until his everyday life is destroyed by the loss of the Lalache. She represents his chance at a normal life and, while he tolerates some erosion of her personality, he rebels when she is taken away.

Haber himself is a personification of the special interest groups and political elites who take advantage of the apathy of latent interest groups (those caught up in the everyday; R. Hardin 1982). Large and imposing, with red hair and beard, Haber is a dream specialist who believes deeply in the power of dreams. With the confident geniality of a therapist, he is the embodiment of well-meaning hubris. Everything in his “plasticoated” office has the veneer of power and success but is fundamentally cheap and flimsy. At first, Haber takes Orr for an average patient, who has a fear of bad dreams due to repressed sexuality or dissatisfaction with life. His interest is piqued as Orr explains the nature of his effective dreaming and, although Haber does not believe Orr, he patronizingly accepts them as an aspect of Orr’s reality. Not a bad man or a necessarily bad therapist, Haber really believes that he will be able to “fix” Orr using a machine he has invented called “the Augmentor”. It feeds brain wave patterns to a subject in order to induce particular states. In this story, Haber uses it to get Orr to dream effectively upon hypnotic suggestion. Already we see that the doctor has no fear about controlling other people’s minds—in fact, he seems to enjoy it.

Haber is all about control, of himself and of others. When first confronted with evidence of the effectiveness of Orr’s dreams, the doctor’s biggest fear is losing control of himself in front of his patient. He cannot even comprehend Orr’s anxiety about his ability to change the world and quickly begins to suggest (hypnotically) that Orr dream up solutions—both to their own individual complaints and to the broader difficulties face by the city and the planet. The problems that Haber takes on through Orr’s dreams are well-known: overpopulation, pollution, resource scarcity, injustice, and conflict. However, with each new effective dream Haber’s own position improves while negative side effects leave many people much worse off. Thus, although Haber is not satisfied with the everyday like Orr, he is willing to accept costs imposed on the rest of society as long as his desire for power and prestige is fulfilled. Of course, Haber does not think of it in this way, but rather engages in a cycle of rationalization as described in the next section.

As mentioned above, the third character, Heather Lelache, is a civil rights attorney brought in by Orr in his initial attempts to avoid VTT with Haber. Orr and Lelache eventually fall in love, but she is not able to help him end Haber’s abuse of his effective dreams. Although she does not appear as frequently as either Orr or Haber, her role exposes one of the most important aspects of Haber’s brave new world.3 Originally a brassy, confident, and somewhat angry woman, Lelache is literally obliterated when Haber suggests that Orr should dream up a solution to the problem of racism. To Haber’s delight, race disappears as all of humanity has always been one color, grey. The child of a white mother and a black father, Lelache cannot exist as herself in this world. It is Orr’s desperation to bring Lelache back into his life that starts him dreaming without Haber. With a little help from his friends, Orr dreams up a grey version of Lelache. Without the complications of race she is a softer and more timid woman, bland, like the still plentiful but uninteresting food that is available on this version of the planet.

The implications of this segment of the story are profound. If Orr represents the public and Haber represents political elites, Lelache represents those marginalized populations who have little or no political power yet experience the highest costs of environmental problems or sustainability transitions. For instance, women bear the largest environmental burden in some countries, but are often socially and politically marginalized and so cannot protect their own interests (Young 2012; Collier, Conway, and Venables 2008; Hultman and Bozmoski 2006). Indigenous peoples in the Arctic or other areas that are vulnerable to climate change tend to have little say in environmental policies at domestic or international levels. Poor people from developing countries also experience heavy costs from climate change but have little ability to change the positions of their governments (e.g. China). At the international level, developing country governments that favor mitigation (e.g. the Maldives) or assistance with adaptation (e.g. the G-70) have little power to either reduce greenhouse gasses directly or to negotiate faster mitigation or adaptation policies (IPCC 2014; Harrison and Sundstrom 2007; Rq, Dqg, and Victor 2016). These are the silent masses who were not named characters in Lathe, but who, like Lelache, simply disappeared as Haber tried time and again to create his ideal world.

The dynamics of policy monopolies, public apathy, and related power disconnects can be a major road block to sustainability transitions. Like Haber, political elites tend to be isolated from the negative impacts of their decisions and may even receive personal benefits in the form of increased prestige, etc. (Ercan and Hendriks 2013; Hendriks 2009). Like Orr, the general public tends to be buried in the everyday and unwilling to engage in political activities until direct threats or harms are felt at home. Yet, both Orr and Haber were insulated from significant harm until the very end of the book, much as the (voting) middle class and political elites tend to be more insulated from environmental problems than the poor in developed and developing countries (IPCC 2014). Lelache represents these marginalized peoples not just in her lack of power to prevent the changes wrought by Haber, but also because she had to rely on Orr to bring her back into the world. Similarly, when power disconnects are wide, marginalized peoples often are first harmed by environmental degradation and then may be forced to bear the costs of mitigation or adaptation as well if their interests are not protected by legal requirements, grassroots movements, or powerful non-governmental organizations.

Cycles of rationalization

Even when disconnects are narrow and there is strong political will, regulatory momentum can be diverted into policy responses that are either ineffective or unjust (or both). Furthermore, these measures can then feed into cycles of rationalization that cause power disconnects to widen, amplifying their negative impacts. The story arc in Lathe illustrates three elements of the cycle of rationalization that can also stand as separate barriers to sustainability transition: silver bullets, side effects, and scapegoats. Silver bullets are policy options that are applied as panaceas—measures that are expected to work regardless of context or application. Side effects can range from displacing environmental harm geographically to shifting the economic costs of a problem to different actors. Scapegoats are factors (or people) that do not actually cause a problem but which are blamed for it. Each of these minor pitfalls can be a problem in its own right, but it is the feedbacks between them that can lead to cascades of destabilizing change. That is, silver bullets usually create negative side effects, which then force decision-makers to rationalize their decisions ex-post using different types of scapegoats. This ensures that those with power retain it and that they fail to learn useful lessons from their mistakes.

The positive feedback associated with cycles of rationalization is clear in Lathe. To begin with, it is difficult to imagine a panacea that would be easier or more powerful than the “effective dreams” of George Orr. All Haber had to do to use these dreams was to hook Orr up to the Augmenter, hypnotize him (Orr was highly susceptible to hypnosis), and suggest a new problem to solve. Orr’s dreaming mind did the rest. Real-world panaceas are not usually so simple, but they do tend to oversimplify, and can include everything from basic command-and-control regulations to “thin” or incomplete applications of otherwise complex, reflexive approaches such as transition management, adaptive management, or co-management (Avelino 2009; Meadowcroft 2011; Frantzeskaki, Loorbach, and Meadowcroft 2012; Cox et al. 2016).

Every time Haber attempts to use Orr’s ability as a silver bullet for the world’s problems, there is a trade-off in the form of negative side effects. As noted above, in Haber’s first attempt to save the planet he gave Orr vague instructions to solve the “population problem” while he was dreaming. The positive effects of the dream were clear. Orr returned home through a much less crowded city to a three-bedroom apartment with its own bathroom and a fridge stocked with more food than he could have imagined before. His body had changed, too, filling out a bit because of the greater availability of food over his longer lifetime. He also enjoyed the feel of a real cotton shirt, which had been an extraordinary luxury just that morning. However, the cost of all this was an epidemic of cancer that had plagued the world years before, an example of how Orr’s dreams change the past to affect the present.

After that fateful session, Orr was wracked with guilt. To him, the benefits of a small population were not worth the cost in lives, but Haber accepted the tradeoffs, even though he also lost several close family members during the “Plague Years”. Again, this is partly because he was psychologically disconnected from others, but two additional factors are also important. First, Haber benefited more from the change than Orr, moving up in status and prestige, as well as improved health, comforts, etc. Indeed, he is transformed from an obscure crank on the fringe of science to a respected researcher on the cutting edge of the well-established field of dream science. Second, Haber attributes the benefits of a lower population to his own action (suggesting the dream to Orr), but blames the negative side effects on Orr’s inability to interpret his instructions correctly. By establishing Orr as the scapegoat, Haber sets up a positive feedback loop in which any benefits from his suggested changes to the world reinforce his identity as benevolent savior—and his entitlement to personal benefits from said changes—while any costs are laid at the feet of the weak and imperfect Orr.

Indeed, having “solved” one problem, Haber is even more determined to use Orr’s dreams to “solve” others. A second side effect of the population dream was an escalation of the war in the Middle East, which was a festering sore before the population dream but was verging on full-scale world war after. Even Brazil was choosing sides in the conflict. Seeing this as a problem caused by Orr’s failures rather than his own “success”, Haber tried to right the new wrong using the same old method; he suggested that Orr should dream of world peace. This, too caused negative side-effects but also allowed Haber to move up in the world, as he was consulted by government ministers in addition to his higher standing in academia.

All of these changes simply fed Haber’s ambition and hubris as the cycle continued. While some things, like geography and the greenhouse effect were outside of Orr’s purview, changes kept piling up as Haber tried one “improvement” after another. Portland became the home of the World Planning Center (WPC) of the supranational Federation of Peoples; a planetary government that had existed since the Plague years. As the capital of the planet, Portland was populated with majestic skyscrapers and government buildings. People from all over the world congregated in the city. In his increasingly “perfect” world, Haber was in charge of the Human Utility: Research and Development Center of the WPC. Otherwise known as HURAD, the center resided in the grandest government building, where the words “The Greatest Good for the Greatest Number” are inscribed boldly in the portico.

There were some benefits to the public at large, too, including large swaths of remaining wilderness, increased biodiversity, clearer air, and less difficult living conditions. However, the costs were also high. As described above, to end racism, Orr’s dreams made everyone gray, obliterating multi-ethic people like Lelache and causing cultural impoverishment. It is also interesting to note that famine continued in less-privileged countries and that the food available for people like Orr and Haber was bland and unappealing, in part because of the lack of diversity but also because of “sustainable” methods used in its production. The end to the war in the Middle East was only brought about by an invasion of rather confused aliens and world peace came at the cost of civilization; after one of Orr’s dreams, TV and other forms of entertainment disappeared to be replaced by a modern-day coliseum, in which spectators sated their blood lust watching sports teams kill each other, rather than going to war. Personal liberty was another victim of Haber’s interventions. Togetherness and civic responsibility became the zeitgeist of the times, and genetic purity the mantra. Certified citizens carried hypoderm guns with which to euthanize criminals on the street. Diseases like cancer became a crime.

With each new set of tradeoffs, the relationship between Orr and Haber becomes more strained. As Orr regains his equilibrium by reconnecting with other human beings, Haber’s “progress” only feeds his insatiable desire for power. Orr’s own empowerment comes a bit too late; he finally refuses to be used by Haber only after the doctor has enough data to use “the Augmenter” to induce effective dreams in ordinary individuals. This allows Haber to eliminate Orr as the instrument—which he does easily by “suggesting” that Orr dream that he doesn’t have effective dreams—and thereby end all of the imperfections supposedly generated by Orr’s resistance to Haber’s plans. By doing so, Haber removes the scapegoat, Orr, but of course does nothing to solve the underlying problem.

As in so many allegories, it is Haber himself who, in this constant drive for improvement, destroys his own creation. Haber’s effective dreams are so disconnected that they threaten the very fabric of the world. Without the power to dream any longer, Orr must save the world the old fashioned way, by ending Haber’s dream. In this he serves as an iconic hero, struggling alone against the maelstrom to turn off the Augmentor, rendering the mad scientist ineffective. Nevertheless, when Orr emerges, he rejoins the rest of society in the struggle to rebuild their lives together, as a community and a polity. This is the lesson he has learned: it is important to help others but only as a member of the group, not as a god-like, well-intentioned tyrant.4

Of course, not all decision-makers are as disconnected as Haber, though power does often lead to Haberian behavior on the part of political elites. There are many bureaucrats, managers, and politicians who don’t let power “go to their heads”, often by maintaining strong connections to the people who and most affected by their decisions (Prendergast 2016; Oberfield 2014). On the other hand, the cycles of rationalization described above do occur frequently and their foundations are well-supported in the literature. Psychological studies show that power can create disconnects. For instance, when average individuals are given power over others they tend to dehumanize those they control, even if there are no derogatory interactions between the groups (Gwinn, Judd, and Park 2013; Zimbardo et al. 1973; Inesi, Gruenfeld, and Galinsky 2012). Furthermore, both high- and low-power individuals tend to remember goal-facilitating information, but high-power individuals tend to forget goal-constraining information much more than low-power individuals (Whitson et al. 2012). It is difficult to tell whether or not there is some element of self-selection here. That is, do individuals gain power because they are able to ignore constraining information or do they start ignoring constraining information when they gain power? Most likely there is a feedback that magnifies pre-existing tendencies as individuals gain power and feel the need to rationalize its use (Oberfield 2012).

Ironically, leaders may create the above psychological disconnects in part because they are so often blamed when collective decisions produce negative side effects (Duch, Przepiorka, and Stevenson 2015). This, dynamic, too, is shown in Lathe. It is easy to place all the responsibility for the horrors described in the story at Haber’s feet, but Orr allowed his effective dreams to be used. Indeed, his ability to scapegoat both Haber and the ATT system as a whole contributed to his apathy. Similarly, powerful latent interest groups can more easily ignore harm to marginalized populations when they can scapegoat political leaders or blame the political system for their inaction. Of course, the need for collective action is a hurdle that cannot be ignored—no individual can wield the power of the majority alone—but the psychology of apathy and the everyday goes much deeper. Powerful elites are only likely to stand up for marginalized populations when they feel some connection to them. In Lathe, Orr decides to take action because he gets to know and love Lelache before she is wrenched away from him by Haber’s well-intentioned use of his dreams. In the real world, marginalized populations are usually the focus of prejudice and bias, rather than love or acceptance, making it easy to target them as scapegoats (Kay et al. 2009). In other words, cycles of rationalization build up antipathies toward scapegoats—whether politicians or marginalized populations—that make it much less likely that the public or powerful elites will step up to demand change. Thus, while the powerful do sometimes stand up for the marginalized—as Orr took action to regain Lelache—it is more likely that they will remain apathetic, either because they do not recognize their own influence (blame is on policy makers/governance institutions) or because they believe the scapegoat narrative (blame is on marginalized populations, environmental factors, etc.), or both.

With this plot, Le Guin was clearly drawing parallels to well-known instances of despotism and dictatorship, but there are also more subtle comparisons to be made. The tension between Orr and Haber is predicated on a rather fantastic metaphor—effective dreaming—but parallels real world power struggles. From Aristotle to Machiavelli to Marx to Putnam and well beyond, political philosophers have taken sides on the appropriate balance between individual and collective action.5 Throughout, the voice of marginalized peoples—the Lelaches of the world—are seldom heard. This section describes the treadmill and then briefly explains how it fits with several literatures. The next section will show how the pitfalls identified in Lathe can cause the treadmill to be “stuck” in an ineffective cycle, prolonging environmental harm and increasing the likelihood of environmental crisis.

As described in the previous section, Le Guin’s book is classic because it captures three fundamental ideal-types in political systems: the public (Orr), decision makers (Haber), and marginalized groups (Lelache/everyone else in the book). In the story, Haber’s hubris, Orr’s inaction, and Lelache’s powerlessness result in escalating cycles of social and environmental harm, culminating in near-catastrophe which finally precipitates fundamental change that could shift the system into restorative rather than destructive cycles. Similar cycles of success and failure are observed in the real world, as decision makers and political entrepreneurs respond to changing signals from different constituencies. While in the book only one full transition is observed (with the end of Haber’s use of effective dreams), real systems tend to move back and forth between ineffective (destructive) cycles and effective (restorative) cycles, though collapse is also possible.

We can refer to this set of cycles within cycles as the governance treadmill. This is an extension of the management treadmill concept described by Webster (2015a; 2015b). The term governance is used to indicate that response can occur through multiple pathways, including informal rules and norms as well as formal regulations or management measures. As shown in Figure 1, the treadmill starts with an environmental problem, which sends signals to political actors, who put pressure on decision makers (increasing political concern), who respond by either maintaining the status quo or by instituting new rules or regulations in order to “solve” the problem. Of course, “solutions” are not always perfect—ineffective silver bullets are often applied—so the problem may continue to increase or side effects may crop up, keeping the system on the ineffective side of the treadmill. However, in some cases, governance response reduces the core problem, which in turn dampens signals and leads to a decline in political concern. The latter can be referred to as a crisis rebound effect (CRE) and may lead to a return to less effective governance and a renewal of the cycle.

Figure 1

The Governance Treadmill. The right-hand side shows an ineffective cycle, in which environmental problems send out socio-economic signals that lead to increasing political concern. As long as governance is ineffective this cycle will continue as the problem increases, signals become stronger, and political concern grows. However, once concern is high enough given available governance options, it is possible to switch to an effective cycle, where the problem decreases, signals weaken, and political concern declines in a process called the crisis rebound effect (CRE). The CRE, along with exogenous factors, can then cause a switch back to the ineffective cycle, starting another rotation of the treadmill, which oscillates between more and less effective environmental governance. Disconnects that block problem signals can delay switching from ineffective to effective cycles while strong institutions can prolong periods of effective governance (not shown). DOI: https://doi.org/10.1525/elementa.212.f1

Figure 1

The Governance Treadmill. The right-hand side shows an ineffective cycle, in which environmental problems send out socio-economic signals that lead to increasing political concern. As long as governance is ineffective this cycle will continue as the problem increases, signals become stronger, and political concern grows. However, once concern is high enough given available governance options, it is possible to switch to an effective cycle, where the problem decreases, signals weaken, and political concern declines in a process called the crisis rebound effect (CRE). The CRE, along with exogenous factors, can then cause a switch back to the ineffective cycle, starting another rotation of the treadmill, which oscillates between more and less effective environmental governance. Disconnects that block problem signals can delay switching from ineffective to effective cycles while strong institutions can prolong periods of effective governance (not shown). DOI: https://doi.org/10.1525/elementa.212.f1

Close modal

Most social-ecological systems move back and forth between effective and ineffective cycles multiple times. Sometimes return to the ineffective cycle is due to the CRE, but exogenous factors such as an increase in demand or the introduction of new technologies can also cause a return to the ineffective side. Then, of course, problem signals would resume and pressure for improved governance would eventually increase again. This oscillation between effective and ineffective management cycles is the governance treadmill. While progress is made in many cases, it is rarely as rapid or as permanent as would be expected under a proactive regime. This is partly due to factors that delay response (see more below), and partly due to factors that undermine effective management, “resetting” the treadmill to its ineffective state. In a few cases, the treadmill might “stop”, usually when economic conditions become unfavorable (e.g. decline in demand, increase in costs of production) or when new technologies effectively negate the underlying problem (e.g. provision of substitutes, pollution control tech, etc.).

While the causes of switching differ from case to case, the pattern of the treadmill is dominant in most issue areas. For instance, Webster (2015a) shows that, in fisheries, economic crisis tends to force management to a more effective cycle but that regulations revert when prices rise or the threat of new entrants is eliminated. For most wildlife trade, education in the US, Europe, and Japan reduced demand in the 1980s/1990s, making it easier to regulate trafficking, but increases in demand from China and other transition economies caused a return to ineffectiveness in the 2000s. For large scale processes like climate change, the treadmill occurs at multiple levels of analysis. Globally, we are still building up political will to implement an effective response, though the 2015 Paris Agreement may be a step in the right direction. Nationally, climate policy often depends on unrelated political trends, such as the back and forth created by public vacillation between democratic and republican candidates in the US.6 At the local level, cities and communities learn through exposure to climate-related extreme events but may also act based on shared environmental norms, though both are subject to economic conditions and related budget constraints (Zahran et al. 2006; Brooks et al. 2014; Brody et al. 2008).

The cycles of the treadmill are not new, though they are rarely explained in just this way. In political science, Russell Hardin (1982; 1995) uses game theory to describe cycles of domination by “elites” that are punctuated by the activation of “latent interest groups”, specifically public majorities or grassroots movements. Baumgartner and Jones (2009; Jones and Baumgartner 2012) show that punctuated equilibrium occurs due to the responsive nature of governance and related cycles of public attention. Similar cycles are also observed in theories of organizational change, particularly those associated with March and Simon (1993). Interestingly, in a recent interview, Bengt Holmstrom, who won the Nobel Prize in Economics for his work on incentives and institutions, described similar cycles of trial and response in both corporate governance and government policy (Inskeep 2016). Predicated on the complex cycles associated with ecological function, the literature on social ecological systems or coupled human and natural systems usually presumes similar cyclical patterns of interaction between environment and society, though these are not always explicitly laid out as shown in the treadmill (Holling 2001; Walker et al. 2004; Ostrom 2007; Liu et al. 2007).

On the sustainability transitions side, early work focused on multi-level analysis is also based in complex systems thinking, with considerable focus on the co-evolution of technology and society. However, this perspective was decidedly apolitical (Geels 2002; Geels 2012). Transition management built on multi-level analysis by providing a policy toolkit designed to facilitate socio-technical transition via the creation of new technological “niches” (Loorbach 2010; Kern and Smith 2008). While stakeholder engagement is a major tool in the TM kit, it has been widely criticized for omitting politics both in theory (Meadowcroft 2011) and in practice (Avelino 2009; Hendriks 2009). A number of authors have worked to bridge this gap, either through institutional design (Hendriks 2016), inclusion of interest group politics (Frantzeskaki, Loorbach, and Meadowcroft 2012), embedding policy making in transition management (Voß 2014), or focusing on a “post-foundational” notion of democracy that goes beyond the voting public to consider representation of stakeholders as minority interest groups that might otherwise be ignored (Jhagroe and Loorbach 2015). Approaches that bring politics into transition management include cycles of signals and response with political ramifications, though the focus largely remains on bureaucratic response to calls for better energy efficiency, and so they do not really capture the full scope of the governance treadmill, or the effects of pitfalls like power disconnects or cycles of rationalization.

The pitfalls described in Lathe cause governance to stay on the ineffective side of the treadmill until the problem becomes so severe that crisis triggers strong action. If there are power disconnects, then problems are only affecting marginalized populations, which means that it takes much longer for political concern to build up and for the system to switch to the more effective cycle. The situation must become either very dire or must spread to larger segments of the population before action is taken. Furthermore, even when powerful groups are affected, the response may be to insulate the privileged by passing costs along to weaker (politically marginalized) or broader (the public) shoulders. This in itself creates disconnects and is essentially what Haber chose to do every time he used Orr’s effective dreams. Rationalizing the choice to ignore negative side effects and force costs onto other groups further widens disconnects by creating psychological barriers to empathy with the suffering of others. When scapegoats are used as part of the process of rationalization, misattribution ensures that responses target the wrong problem and so are necessarily ineffective. This is what happens when Haber blames Orr for negative side effects, rather than realizing that the method of effective dreaming by a disconnected individual is inherently flawed.

Patterns that parallel the prolonged, ineffective cycles described in Lathe are common in the real world, where disconnects and cycles of rationalization play a major role in preventing effective governance of the environment, the economy, and society. From ancient times, conflict over resources and political power caused one group of humans to rationalize the mistreatment of other groups of humans, building up social structures that perpetuate hierarchical power structures. Take the eradication and subjugation of indigenous peoples under colonialism. We tend to think of this as an artifact of the time; a result of pervasive racism and cruelty, which was certainly a part of the structural context. However, there were those in Spain and elsewhere who made moral arguments against the killing, enslaving, and displacement of indigenous peoples. In fact, there was an entire discourse on the topic during the period, so elites had the opportunity to think past their inherited prejudices and choose a less harmful course. Nevertheless, the racist, theocratic storyline won because it provided decision makers with the best rationale for their choice to benefit from the suffering of others (Fitzmaurice 2014). This in turn perpetuated systemic injustice and related environmental degradation by keeping the treadmill in an ineffective cycle. Moreover, the effects were lasting, as many of the widest disconnects still in existence today were created during this period.

With industrialization in Europe and North America, new disconnects were created, sending the treadmill down an even more destructive path. Elites began rationalizing the unequal effects of pollution on human health and ecosystem function as well as the appropriation of resources. They found ways to justify the enclosure of public land, displacement of peasants to the sweat shops of the cities, and the pollution and squalor that met them there (Buck 2010). Jobs, progress, and the wealth of nations were frequent rationale for the continuation of these negative side effects—or what economists would call externalities. Interestingly, when pollution affected elites, they chose either to move away from pollution sources (and often out of inner cities) or to advocate for laws to reduce the pollution problem. Early environmental laws addressed pollution by moving the source industries away from wealthier neighborhoods and into poorer areas. However, as workers grew in numbers and in resources, their political power increased. Local-scale regulations to reduce pollution through factory controls (rather than relocation) were passed in many cities of Europe, the US, and other industrialized countries, switching the system to a more effective cycle for a period of time, though the treadmill continues to oscillate to this day (Bullard 2005; Taylor 2014; Thorsheim 2006; Wilkening 2004; Cable and Benson 1993).

In the last century, environmental degradation increased rapidly with industrialization and economic growth in other parts of the world. Local elites in emerging economies again rationalized the negative effects of industrialization as necessary evils associated with progress. In China, the communist-capitalist elites learned from the experience of Britain, arguing that “sheep ate people” during the enclosures that forced peasants to make way for wool production during the Industrial Revolution and that the same type of sacrifice is a pivotal part of this stage in their own development (Zhao 2004). Growing environmental crisis is now sparking environmental concern in China and other emergent economies, contributing to improved response both at the domestic and international levels (Wang 2015; Huan 2014; Cunningham 2015; Phillips 2016). Of course, these successes are not universal and they come with their own side effects, including the displacement of polluting activities to politically marginalized areas (Wu et al. 2016; Cai, Chen, and Gong 2016).

At the same time, it is important to remember that China is making products for consumers in the US, Europe, Japan and other developed countries as well as for domestic consumption, so rationalization is also occurring at the international level. Both consumers and regulators turn a blind eye to problems in the developing world, with a few exceptional cases of outrage like the Nike sweatshops crisis of the 1990s or recent allegations regarding Apple’s abuse of workers in China (Newell 2005; Carmin et al. 2011; Frost and Burnett 2007; Dauvergne 2005). Periodic press coverage of similar events has generated considerable pressure to “green” business via corporate social responsibility, with greater or lesser success, depending on the corporation, but political responses were minimal (Pogutz 2008; Gallagher and Weinthal 2012).

The green business movement is similar to Orr’s awakening and his attempts to protect Lelache, both in intent and in insufficiency. The number of businesses producing sustainability reports, working to create products that are less harmful to the environment, and even seeking to be “restorative” via ecological innovation has skyrocketed over the last two decades, in part due to consumer demand for greener, and healthier products (Makower 2016). This is a good thing. However, many are skeptical about the efficacy of this economic process, both due to the prevalence of “greenwashing” and due to the difficulties of changing consumer behavior and purchasing patterns (Clarke and Boersma 2015; Dauvergne 2016; Van Den Bergh, Truffer, and Kallis 2011). That is, consumers need to buy less, as well as buying green, but this is a much more difficult cultural change. Another concern is the potential for “green” consumerism provide rationalization for apathy: buying “green” products substitutes for more onerous political actions or changes in individual-level behavior (Lewis 2008; Schudson 2007). This is a form of moral license, where doing something “good” gives an individual the ability to rationalize subsequent “bad” behavior (Cascio and Plant 2015).

Academia has its fair share of Haberesque rationalizations as well. Perhaps most well-known is the “tragedy of the commons”, propounded by Hardin (1968) as an allegory for what he saw as the problem of overpopulation, which he blamed directly on the poor. This focus on population as a major environmental problem takes the spotlight off affluence, which allows a single person in a developed country to consume, and waste, much more than the average person in a developing country (Sachs 2015). In other words, poor people make easy scapegoats for our environmental problems (Dauvergne 2016).

Even if we discount Hardin’s prejudice, the tragedy of the commons essentially blames environmental degradation on local resource-users, ignoring the ample evidence that the worst levels of overexploitation and pollution occur when powerful outsiders come in to exploit local conditions (Buck 2010; Berkes et al. 2006). Indeed, Elinor Ostrom won a Nobel Prize in economics for showing that connected communities that experience signals directly from environmental problems are usually good at managing the commons by setting their own rules of access—as long as they are protected from outside interference by disconnected groups (Ostrom 1990). Consumers, too, are absolved from blame by this storyline, even though their demand for products creates the incentives to overexploit and to lobby for regulations that allow for overexploitation (Webster 2015a; Dauvergne 2008). Nevertheless, the tragedy of the commons is the storyline we prefer because it pardons both decision makers and the public, placing responsibility squarely on the shoulders of (partially responsible) scapegoats.

The widest disconnects occur when large segments of the public engage in a cycle of rationalization at the same time as decision makers. Such movements frequently target marginalized populations as the “cause” of some perceived harm. It wasn’t just decision-makers who blamed slaves for their status in society; it was also slave owners and the vast majority of the public who benefited from the practice of slavery in the Americas (Fredrickson 1989; Patterson 1982; Morgan 2003). Similarly, it was not just the Nazi party who blamed the Jews and other “impure” races for Germany’s decline, it was also a large portion of the German population (Diner 2000; Crew 1994). History records many other examples of prolonged conflict due, at least in part, to group polarization, where cycles of rationalization reinforce scapegoating on both sides (Sunstein 2009; Hoffmann 1986; Simon 1995).

Even with the increase in deliberative democracy in recent decades, the public can be persuaded to engage in cycles of rationalization centered on “identity politics”, which is ultimately the scapegoating of others (Dryzek 2005). In 2016, it was a majority of the British people who voted for the exit of Britain from the European Union, joining with some politicians in blaming the EU and immigrants for systemic economic difficulties (Henderson et al. 2016; Goodwin 2016). Similarly, in the 2016 US elections, populist candidates on the left (Sanders) and right (Trump) were supported by (some) people who cast all blame for the increasing inequality in the US on either corporations and corrupt politicians (left) or on immigrants, Muslims, and corrupt politicians (right). Indeed, Trump won the majority of votes in the Electoral College in part because of his scapegoating rhetoric (Muller 2016). While some of these scapegoats bear partial responsibility for current economic conditions (i.e., specific corporations and corrupt politicians), both explanations ignore years of public apathy, systemic flaws in the US government, and fundamental difficulties associated with representative democracy. This is not to say that all supporters of either candidate take such simplistic positions, just that much of their political popularity is due to relatively simplistic, “kick the bastards out” narratives.

A full analysis of the rationale for political backlash is beyond the scope of this paper, but one very important point needs to be made: empowerment of the marginalized often threatens the privileged. This can be seen in all of the broad cycles described above as well as in more specific cases. For instance, many on the far right in the US and in Europe are expressing fear of cultural loss and loss of economic opportunity due to influxes of migrants, increases in terror attacks, and anti-racism protests.7 People deal with this perceived loss of power and resulting lack of control in multiple ways, but an important compensating mechanism is the construction of spurious causal narratives, often including some type of scapegoat. Preference for simple explanation of complex issues (like climate change) has also been documented (Landau, Kay, and Whitson 2015; Meadows 2008; Brock and Carpenter 2007; Kay et al. 2009). At a smaller scale, participatory processes often fail to empower the marginalized because of resistance from those who are asked to relinquish influence or because the powerless are not really free to express their concerns when confronting the powerful (Avelino 2009). Though not reflected in Lathe, these aspects of the governance treadmill should not be ignored.

From this brief analysis, we can expect sustainability transitions to involve political as well as socio-technological steps forward and backward, as described by the governance treadmill. This results from the constant dance between singular action by elites, who often fall into the Haberian ideal type, and collective action by the public majority, which, once roused from apathy, may take an Orrian stance in defense of marginalized populations, as represented by Lelache in the story. However, unlike Lathe, the majority may instead choose to scapegoat those who have little power to defend themselves, starting off new cycles of rationalization. It is these cycles that are most devastating and could completely derail the sustainability enterprise. Thus, understanding sustainability transitions also means exploring many variations of the governance treadmill.

Le Guin’s story highlights two major pitfalls (power disconnects and cycles of rationalization) and three minor roadblocks (silver bullets, side effects, and scapegoats) that tend to keep the governance treadmill stuck in an ineffective cycle. First, power disconnects occur when the people making decisions are insulated from the costs imposed by environmental problems. As a disconnected person, Haber was able to accept high costs to others for great benefits to himself when he appropriated Orr’s “effective dreams” to his own supposedly altruistic ends. At the same time, Orr’s apathy allowed this abuse of his power and ultimately the near-destruction of the world. Second, these disconnects can be widened by cycles of rationalization, in which decision makers choose to accept credit for the positive consequences of the silver bullet solutions that they implement, while blaming negative side effects on scapegoats. Scapegoats are particularly important in cycles of rationalization and may even be the same marginalized groups who are most harmed by an environmental problem.

A number of these pitfalls are already reflected in the literature, but there are some important new insights. Injunctions to narrow disconnects by including those who are most affected in decision-making processes are numerous (Reed 2008; Berkes 2003; Hendriks 2016; Jhagroe and Loorbach 2015; Klein et al. 2011). Warnings to avoid silver bullets and panaceas abound as well (Young 2001; Ostrom 2007; Liu et al. 2007). There are also several frameworks and toolkits available to help communities, decision makers, and international regimes select and implement measures that get at the heart of environmental problems while minimizing negative side effects (Folke et al. 2005; Loorbach 2010). In addition, there is a growing literature on climate skepticism and the political psychology of rationalizing environmental degradation more broadly (Jacques 2009; Dunlap 2013; Dauvergne 2016).

However, cycles of rationalization are less well-understood, and the larger process of the management treadmill needs more study. Bridging the divides between these disparate literatures would be an important step forward, as would studies designed to explicitly delve into the political as well as social, economic, and technological aspects of transition (Frantzeskaki, Loorbach, and Meadowcroft 2012; Kern 2011). Given the important role played by the public in many environmental governance decisions it would also be useful to draw more from social psychology, particularly in relation to public (rather than stakeholder) response to large-sale environmental uncertainties (e.g. Whitson, Galinsky, and Kay 2015; Kay et al. 2009; Landau, Kay, and Whitson 2015). Several factors, including compensatory control mechanisms and group biases could generate considerable backlash against environmental governance even as we experience more and more environmental harm. This would completely derail the governance treadmill and could lead to even greater global crisis.

At a different level, adding emotional appeal to the lessons provided by the literature could help to drive them home (Keller, Siegrist, and Gutscher 2006). Lathe provides vivid imagery of terrible environmental consequences of both too little collective action and too much imposition of a singular will on society. At the same time, this book also reflects deep truths about human response to large-scale problems. In the ideal-types of Haber, Orr, and Lelache, Le Guin gives us a new storyline; one in which the powerful are clearly to blame; either for their actions (Haber) or for their inaction (Orr). She shows us how power corrupts, but also how apathy and the acceptance of social constraints allows that corruption. Furthermore, in the narrative surrounding Lelache and Orr, she shows how connecting the public to marginalized peoples can be a countervailing force for change. In the end, Lathe describes a cyclical process of destruction, but also provides a hope for a more connected and a more sustainable world.

See Galbreath (1980) for a literary discussion of concepts such as holism and the use of the occult as metaphor in Le Guin’s works.

In other words, Giddens says that social interaction creates institutions, norms, regulations, etc. but then these governance structures in turn shape human behavior, limiting the range of possible actions by assigning power to different actors, limiting the actions available, etc.

See Johnston (1999) for a more complete (and literary) comparison between Le Guin’s Lathe of Heaven and Orwell’s 1984.

Huntington (1975) asserts that Le Guin is really placing the private world above the public world, since all public actions “lead to failure”. Aside from the omission of Orr’s last public act, the salvation of Haber & the world, this ignores almost all of the interactions between Orr and the aliens which suggest that it is Orr’s spiritual reconnection with the rest of the world that saves him.

Jameson (2009) actually posits that Lathe of Heaven reflects Le Guin’s own Jeffersonian and Thoreauvian criticism of the growing welfare state in the US. In contrast Theall (1975) claims that Le Guin is using Marxian dialectic approaches in building, destroying, and rebuilding the various worlds of Lathe. Both are incorrect in that they ignore Le Guin’s own references to Daoist political philosophy throughout the book. Huntington (1975) captures this briefly when he links Haber’s failure to save the world to his failure to recognize himself as a “unification of opposites”.

Small island developing states and other countries that are particularly vulnerable to climate change are often exceptions to this pattern. Yet even in countries like the Maldives, shifts from one ruling party to another can lead to large swings in climate policy.

While some conservative populists may believe that they are marginalized themselves, this is usually the result of a feeling of entitlement and nostalgia for a past when they were in positions of privilege, particularly due to racial and gendered governance structures, as much if not more than regional or sectoral economic conditions (Hochschild 2016; Cramer 2016). It is also important to note that media narratives tend to be misleading about the distribution of voters. Take the US presidential election; while it is true that the narrow margins in several states increased the importance of rural, white, lower-income voters, the bulk of support for Trump was still with middle and upper-class elites (Huang et al. 2016; Kusmin 2012). This is, ironically, another form of scapegoating that is perpetuated by the media and accepted by elites on both sides of the aisle because it plays into common stereotypes.

This paper was strengthened by feedback from the journal editor, co-editors for this special-issue, and several anonymous reviewers.

The author has no competing interests to declare.

1
Avelino
 
F
Empowerment and the Challenge of Applying Transition Management to Ongoing Projects
Policy Sciences
2009
, vol. 
42
 
4
(pg. 
369
-
90
)
2
Baumgartner
 
FR
Bryan
 
DJ
Agendas and Instability in American Politics
2009
2nd ed.
Chicago
University of Chicago Press
3
Berkes
 
F
Alternatives to Conventional Management: Lessons from Small Scale Fisheries
Environments
2003
, vol. 
3
 
1
(pg. 
5
-
19
)
4
Berkes
 
F
Hughes
 
TP
Steneck
 
RS
Wilson
 
AJ
Bellwood
 
DR
Gunderson
 
LH
Leslie
 
HM
et al. 
Globalization, Roving Bandits, and Marine Resources
Science
2006
, vol. 
311
 
5767
(pg. 
1557
-
58
)
5
Brock
 
WA
Stephen
 
RC
Panaceas and Diversification of Environmental Policy
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America
2007
, vol. 
104
 
39
(pg. 
15206
-
11
)
6
Brody
 
SD
Sammy
 
Z
Arnold
 
V
Himanshu
 
G
Examining the Relationship between Physical Vulnerability and Public Perceptions of Global Climate Change
Environment And Behavior
2008
, vol. 
40
 
1
(pg. 
72
-
95
)
7
Brooks
 
J
Douglas
 
O
Arnold
 
V
Sammy
 
Z
Charles
 
L
Abnormal Daily Temperature and Concern about Climate Change Across the United States
Review of Policy Research
2014
, vol. 
31
 
3
(pg. 
199
-
217
)
8
Buck
 
SJ
Conca
 
K
Dabelko
 
GD
No Tragedy on the Commons, 
Green Planet Blues: Four Decades of Global Environmental Politics
2010
4th ed.
Boulder
Westview Press
(pg. 
46
-
54
)
9
Bullard
 
RD
The Quest for Environmental Justice
2005
San Francisco
University of California Press
10
Cable
 
S
Michael
 
B
Acting Locally: Environmental Injustice and the Emergence of Grass-Roots Environmental Organizations
Social Problems
1993
, vol. 
40
 
4
(pg. 
464
-
77
)
11
Cai
 
H
Yuyu
 
C
Qing
 
G
Polluting Thy Neighbor: Unintended Consequences of China’s Pollution Reduction Mandates, 
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
2016
Elsevier
, vol. 
76
 (pg. 
86
-
104
)
12
Carmin
 
J
Julian
 
A
Environmental Inequalities Beyond Borders: Local Perspectives on Global Injustice
2011
Cambridge, MA
MIT Press
13
Cascio
 
J
Ashby
 
PE
Prospective Moral Licensing: Does Anticipating Doing Good Later Allow You to Be Bad Now?
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology
2015
, vol. 
56
 (pg. 
110
-
16
)
14
Clarke
 
T
Martijn
 
B
The Governance of Global Value Chains: Unresolved Human Rights, Environmental and Ethical Dilemmas in the Apple Supply Chain, 
Journal of Business Ethics
2015
Netherlands
Springer
July
15
Collier
 
P
Gordon
 
C
Tony
 
V
Climate Change and Africa
Oxford Review of Economic Policy
2008
, vol. 
24
 
2
(pg. 
337
-
53
)
16
Cox
 
M
Sergio
 
V-T
Graham
 
E
Louisa
 
E
Natalie
 
CB
Forrest
 
F
Mateja
 
N
Gustavo
 
G-L
Synthesizing Theories of Natural Resource Management and Governance
Global Environmental Change
2016
, vol. 
39
 (pg. 
45
-
56
)
17
Cramer
 
KJ
The Politics of Resentment: Rural Wisconsin and the Rise of Scott Walker
2016
Chicago
University of Chicago Press
18
Crew
 
DF
Nazism and German Society, 1933–1945
1994
New York
Routledge
19
Cunningham
 
EA
China’s New Plans for a Cap and Trade System Just Might Work
Foreign Policy
2015
October
6
https://foreignpolicy.com/2015/10/06/china-carbon-emissions-climate-change-cap-trade-us/
20
Dauvergne
 
P
Dying of Consumption: Accidents or Sacrifices of Global Morality?
Global Environmental Politics
2005
, vol. 
5
 
3
(pg. 
35
-
47
)
21
Dauvergne
 
P
The Shadows of Consumption: Consequences for the Global Environment
2008
Cambridge, MA
MIT Press
22
Dauvergne
 
P
Environmentalism of the Rich
2016
Cambridge, MA
MIT Press
23
de Gooyert
 
V
Etiënne
 
R
van Kranenburg
 
H
Edward
 
F
van Breen
 
H
Sustainability Transition Dynamics: Towards Overcoming Policy Resistance
Technological Forecasting and Social Change
2016
24
Diner
 
D
Beyond the Conceivable: Studies on Germany, Nazism, and the Holocaust
2000
Los Angeles
University of California Press
25
Dryzek
 
JS
Deliberative Democracy in Divided Societies: Alternatives to Agonism and Analgesia
Political Theory
2005
, vol. 
33
 
2
(pg. 
218
-
42
)
26
Duch
 
R
Wojtek
 
P
Randolph
 
S
Responsibility Attribution for Collective Decision Makers
American Journal of Political Science
2015
, vol. 
59
 
2
(pg. 
372
-
89
)
27
Dunlap
 
RE
Climate Change Skepticism and Denial: An Introduction
American Behavioral Scientist
2013
, vol. 
57
 
6
(pg. 
691
-
98
)
28
Ercan
 
SA
Carolyn
 
MH
The Democratic Challenges and Potential of Localism: Insights from Deliberative Democracy
Policy Studies
2013
, vol. 
34
 
4
(pg. 
422
-
40
)
29
Fitzmaurice
 
A
Sovereignty, Property and Empire, 1500–2000
2014
Cambridge
Cambridge University Press
30
Folke
 
C
Thomas
 
H
Per
 
O
Jon
 
N
Olssonm
 
P
Jon
 
N
Adaptive Governance of Social-Ecoloigcal Systems
Annual Review of Environment and Resources
2005
, vol. 
30
 (pg. 
441
-
73
)
31
Frantzeskaki
 
N
Loorbach
 
D
Meadowcroft
 
J
Governing Societal Transitions to Sustainability
International Journal of Sustainable Development
2012
, vol. 
15
 
1–2
(pg. 
19
-
36
)
32
Fredrickson
 
GM
The Arrogance of Race: Historical Perspectives on Slavery, Racism, and Social Inequality
1989
Hanover, NH
Wesleyan University Press
33
Frost
 
S
Margaret
 
B
Case Study: The Apple iPod in China
Corporate Social Responsibility and Environmental Management
2007
, vol. 
14
 
2
(pg. 
103
-
13
)
34
Galbreath
 
R
Holism, Openness and the Other: Le Guin’s Use of the Occult
Science-Fiction Studies
1980
, vol. 
7
 
1
(pg. 
36
-
48
)
35
Gallagher
 
D
Erika
 
W
Steinberg
 
PE
VanDeveer
 
SD
Business-State Relations and the Environment: The Evolving Role of Corporate Social Responsibility, 
Comparative Environmental Politics: Theory Practice and Prospects
2012
1st ed.
Cambridge
MIT Press
(pg. 
143
-
70
)
36
Geels
 
FW
Technological Transitions as Evolutionary Reconfiguration Processes: A Multi-Level Perspective and a Case-Study
Research Policy
2002
, vol. 
31
 
8–9
(pg. 
1257
-
74
)
37
Geels
 
FW
A Socio-Technical Analysis of Low-Carbon Transitions: Introducing the Multi-Level Perspective into Transport Studies
Journal of Transport Geography
2012
, vol. 
24
 (pg. 
471
-
82
)
38
Giddens
 
A
Central Problems in Social Theory: Action, Structure, and Contradiction in Social Analysis
1979
Berkeley, CA
University of California Press
39
Goodwin
 
A
Brexit and Immigration
Economic Outlook
2016
, vol. 
40
 
2
(pg. 
20
-
25
)
40
Gwinn
 
JD
Charles
 
MJ
Bernadette
 
P
Less Power = Less Human? Effects of Power Differentials on Dehumanization
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology
2013
, vol. 
49
 
3
(pg. 
464
-
70
)
41
Hardin
 
G
Tradgedy of the Commons
Science
1968
, vol. 
162
 
3859
(pg. 
1243
-
48
)
42
Hardin
 
R
Collective Action
1982
Baltimore
Johns Hopkins University
43
Hardin
 
R
One for All: The Logic of Group Conflict
1995
Princeton, NJ
Princeton University Press
44
Harrison
 
K
Lisa
 
MS
The Comparative Politics of Climate Change
Global Environmental Politics
2007
, vol. 
7
 
4
(pg. 
1
-
18
)
45
Heidegger
 
M
Stambaugh
 
Joan
Being and Time
2010
Albany, NY
State University of New York Press
46
Henderson
 
A
Charlie
 
J
Robert
 
L
Roger
 
S
Daniel
 
W
Richard
 
WJ
England, Englishness and Brexit
Political Quarterly
2016
, vol. 
87
 
2
(pg. 
187
-
99
)
47
Hendriks
 
CM
Policy Design without Democracy? Making Democratic Sense of Transition Management
Policy Sciences
2009
, vol. 
42
 
4
(pg. 
341
-
68
)
48
Hendriks
 
CM
Coupling Citizens and Elites in Deliberative Systems: The Role of Institutional Design
European Journal of Political Research
2016
, vol. 
55
 
1
(pg. 
43
-
60
)
49
Hirschman
 
AO
Exit, Voice, and the Fate of the German Democratic Republic: An Essay in Conceptual History
World Politics
1993
, vol. 
45
 
2
(pg. 
173
-
202
)
50
Hochschild
 
AR
Strangers in Their Own Land
2016
New York
New Press
51
Hoffmann
 
S
On the Political Psychology of Peace and War: A Critique and an Agenda
Political Psychology
1986
, vol. 
7
 
1
(pg. 
1
-
21
)
52
Holling
 
CS
Understanding the Complexity of Economic, Ecological, and Social Systems
Ecosystems
2001
, vol. 
4
 (pg. 
390
-
405
)
53
Huang
 
J
Samuel
 
J
Michael
 
S
Rebecca Lai
 
KK
Election 2016: Exit Polls
The New York Times
2016
November
8
 
54
Huan
 
Q
Development of the Red–Green Environmental Movement in China: A Preliminary Analysis
Capitalism Nature Socialism
2014
, vol. 
25
 
3
(pg. 
45
-
60
)
55
Hultman
 
NE
Alexander
 
SB
The Globalization of Disaster: The Changing Face of Normal Disaster: Risk, Resilience and Natural Security in a Changing Climate
Journal of International Affairs
2006
, vol. 
59
 
2
(pg. 
25
-
41
)
56
Huntington
 
J
Public and Private Imperatives in Le Guin’s Novels
Science Fiction Studies
1975
, vol. 
2
 
3
(pg. 
237
-
43
)
57
Inesi
 
ME
Deborah
 
HG
Adam
 
DG
How Power Corrupts Relationships: Cynical Attributions for Others’ Generous Acts
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology
2012
, vol. 
48
 
4
(pg. 
795
-
803
)
58
Inskeep
 
S
Nobel Prize-Winning Thoughts On Incentives And The Importance Of Contracts, 
Morning Edition
2016
National Public Radio
October
12
59
IPCC
Field
 
CB
Barros
 
VR
Dokken
 
DJ
Mach
 
KJ
Mastrandrea
 
MD
Bilir
 
TE
Chatterjee
 
M
et al. 
Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
2014
Cambridge, UK
Cambrdige University Press
, vol. 
1
 
60
Jacques
 
PJ
Environmental Skepticism: Ecoloy, Power and Public Life
2009
Farnham, UK
Ashgate
61
Jameson
 
F
World-Reduction in Le Guin : The Emergence of Utopian Narrative
Science
2009
, vol. 
2
 
3
(pg. 
221
-
30
)
62
Jhagroe
 
S
Derk
 
L
See No Evil, Hear No Evil: The Democratic Potential of Transition Management
Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions
2015
, vol. 
15
 (pg. 
65
-
83
)
63
Johnston
 
L
‘Orr’ and ‘Orwell’: Le Guin’s The Lathe of Heaven and Orwell’s Nineteen Eighty-Four
Extrapolation
1999
, vol. 
40
 
4
(pg. 
351
-
54
)
64
Jones
 
BD
Frank
 
RB
Representation and Agenda Setting
The Policy Studies Journal
2004
, vol. 
32
 
1
pg. 
24
 
65
Jones
 
BD
Frank
 
RB
From There to Here?: Punctuated Equilibrium to the General Punctuation Thesis to a Theory of Government
Policy Studies Journal
2012
, vol. 
40
 
1
(pg. 
1
-
19
)
66
Kay
 
AC
Jennifer
 
AW
Danielle
 
G
Adam
 
DG
Compensatory Control: Achieving Order through the Mind, Our Institutions, and the Heavens
Current Directions in Psychological Science
2009
, vol. 
18
 
5
(pg. 
264
-
68
)
67
Keller
 
C
Michael
 
S
Heinz
 
G
The Role of the Affect and Availability Heuristics in Risk Communication
Risk Analysis
2006
, vol. 
26
 
3
(pg. 
631
-
39
)
68
Kern
 
F
Ideas, Institutions, and Interests: Explaining Policy Divergence in Fostering ‘System Innovations’ towards Sustainability
Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy
2011
, vol. 
29
 
6
(pg. 
1116
-
34
)
69
Kern
 
F
Adrian
 
S
Restructuring Energy Systems for Sustainability? Energy Transition Policy in the Netherlands
Energy Policy
2008
, vol. 
36
 
11
(pg. 
4093
-
4103
)
70
Kingdon
 
JW
Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies
2011
3rd ed.
Boston
Longman
71
Klein
 
KJ
Andrew
 
PK
Jonathan
 
CZ
Beng
 
CL
Jessica
 
LS
When Team Members’ Values Differ: The Moderating Role of Team Leadership
Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes
2011
, vol. 
114
 
1
(pg. 
25
-
36
)
72
Kusmin
 
L
Rural America at a Glance, 
2012
USDA-ERS Economic Brief
73
Landau
 
MJ
Kay
 
AC
Whitson
 
JA
Compensatory Control and the Appeal of a Structured World
Psychological Bulletin
2015
, vol. 
141
 
3
(pg. 
694
-
722
)
74
Le Guin
 
U
The Lathe of Heaven
1976
New York
HarperCollins
75
Lewis
 
T
Transforming Citizens? Green Politics and Ethical Consumption on Lifestyle Television
Continuum
2008
, vol. 
22
 (pg. 
227
-
40
) 
(July 2015)
76
Liu
 
J
Thomas
 
D
Stephen
 
RC
Carl
 
F
Marina
 
A
Charles
 
LR
Stephen
 
HS
et al. 
Coupled Human and Natural Systems
Ambio
2007
, vol. 
36
 
8
(pg. 
639
-
49
)http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/18240679
77
Loorbach
 
D
Transition Management for Sustainable Development: A Prescriptive, Complexity-Based Governance Framework
Governance, An International Journal of Policy, Administration, and Institutions
2010
, vol. 
23
 
1
(pg. 
161
-
83
)
78
Makower
 
J
State of Green Business 2016
2016
GreenBiz.com
79
March
 
JG
Herbert
 
AS
Organizations
1993
2nd ed.
Cambridge
Blackwell Business Publishers
80
Meadowcroft
 
J
Engaging with the Politics of Sustainability Transitions
Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions
2011
, vol. 
1
 
1
(pg. 
70
-
75
)
81
Meadows
 
DH
Wright
 
D
Thinking in Systems: A Primer
2008
White River Junction, VT
Chelsea Green Publishing
82
Morgan
 
ES
American Slavery, American Freedom
2003
New York
W. W. Norton & Company
83
Muller
 
J-W
What Is Populism?
2016
Philadelphia
University of Pennsylvania Press
84
Newell
 
P
Race, Class and the Global Politics of Environmental Inequality
Global Enviornmental Politics
2005
, vol. 
5
 
5
(pg. 
70
-
95
)
85
Oberfield
 
ZW
Socialization and Self-Selection: How Police Officers Develop Their Views About Using Force
Administration & Society
2012
, vol. 
44
 
6
(pg. 
702
-
30
)
86
Oberfield
 
ZW
Becoming Bureaucrats
2014
Philadelphia
University of Pennsylvania Press
87
Ostrom
 
E
Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action
1990
Cambridge
Cambridge University Press
88
Ostrom
 
E
A Diagnostic Approach for Going beyond Panaceas
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America
2007
, vol. 
104
 
39
(pg. 
15181
-
87
)
89
Patterson
 
O
Slavery and Social Death
1982
Cambridge, MA
Harvard University Press
90
Phillips
 
T
China Ratifies Paris Climate Change Agreement ahead of G20
The Guardian
2016
September
3
91
Pogutz
 
S
Utting
 
P
Clapp
 
J
Sustainable Development, Corporate Sustainability, and Corporate Social Responsibility: The Missing Link, 
Corporate Accountability and Sustainable Development
2008
New York
Oxford University Press
(pg. 
34
-
60
)
92
Prendergast
 
C
The Motivation and Bias of Bureaucrats
The American Economic Review
2016
, vol. 
97
 
1
(pg. 
180
-
96
)
93
Reed
 
MS
Stakeholder Participation for Environmental Management: A Literature Review
Biological Conservation
2008
, vol. 
141
 
10
(pg. 
2417
-
31
)
94
Sabatier
 
PA
Anne
 
MB
Sabatier
 
PA
Jenkins-Smith
 
HC
From Vague Consensus to Clearly Differentiated Coalitions: Environmental Policy at Lake Taho, 1964–1985, 
Policy Change and Learning: An Advocacy Coalition Approach
1993
Boulder
Westview Press
(pg. 
177
-
210
)
95
Sachs
 
JD
The Age of Sustainable Development
2015
New York
Columbia University Press
96
Schudson
 
M
Citizens, Consumers, and the Good Society
The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science
2007
, vol. 
611
 
1
(pg. 
236
-
49
)
97
Seckinelgin
 
H
The Environment and International Politics: International Fisheries, Heidegger, and Social Method
2006
New York
Routledge
98
Simon
 
HA
Rationality in Political Behavior
Political Psychology
1995
, vol. 
16
 
1
(pg. 
45
-
61
)
99
Sunstein
 
CR
Deliberative Trouble? Why Groups Go to Extremes
Yale Law Journal
2009
, vol. 
110
 
1
(pg. 
71
-
119
)
100
Taylor
 
DE
Toxic Communities
2014
New York
New York University Press
101
Theall
 
DF
The Art of Social-Science Fiction: The Ambiguous Utopian Dialectics of Ursula K. Le Guin
Science Fiction Studies
1975
, vol. 
2
 
3
(pg. 
256
-
64
)
102
Thorsheim
 
P
Inventing Pollution
2006
Athens, OH
Ohio University Press
103
Van Den
 
B
Jeroen
 
CJM
Bernhard
 
T
Giorgos
 
K
Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions: Introduction and Overview
Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions
2011
, vol. 
1
 
1
(pg. 
1
-
23
)
104
Victor
 
DG
Toward Effective International Cooperation on Climate Change: Numbers, Interests and Institutions
Global Environmental Politics
2016
, vol. 
6
 
3
(pg. 
90
-
103
)
105
Voß
 
J-P
Performative Policy Studies: Realizing ‘transition Management.’
Innovation: The European Journal of Social Science Research
2014
, vol. 
27
 
4
(pg. 
317
-
43
)
106
Voß
 
J-P
Basil
 
B
The Politics of Reflexive Governance?: Challenges for Designing Adaptive
Ecology And Society
2011
, vol. 
16
 
2
pg. 
9
  
107
Walker
 
B
Holling
 
CS
Stephen
 
RC
Ann
 
K
Resilience, Adaptability and Transformability in Social-Ecological Systems
Ecology And Society
2004
, vol. 
9
 
2
pg. 
5
  
108
Wang
 
X
Requests for Environmental Information Disclosure in China: An Understanding from Legal Mobilization and Citizen Activism
Journal of Contemporary China
2015
March
, vol. 
564
 (pg. 
1
-
15
)
109
Webster
 
DG
Beyond the Tragedy in Global Fisheries
2015a
Cambrdge
MIT Press
110
Webster
 
DG
The Action Cycle/Structural Context Framework: A Fisheries Application
2015b
, vol. 
20
 
1
pg. 
33
 
111
Whitson
 
JA
Adam
 
DG
Aaron
 
K
The Emotional Roots of Conspiratorial Perceptions, System Justification, and Belief in the Paranormal
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology
2015
, vol. 
56
 (pg. 
89
-
95
)
112
Whitson
 
JA
Katie
 
AL
Adam
 
DG
Joe
 
CM
Deborah
 
HG
Brian
 
C
The Blind Leading: Power Reduces Awareness of Constraints
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology
2012
, vol. 
49
 
3
(pg. 
579
-
82
)
113
Wilkening
 
KE
Acid Rain Science and Politics in Japan
2004
Cambridge, MA
MIT Press
114
Wu
 
H
Huanxiu
 
G
Bing
 
Z
Maoliang
 
B
Westward Movement of New Polluting Firms in China: Pollution Reduction Mandates and Location Choice
Journal of Comparative Economics
2016
(pg. 
1
-
20
)
115
Young
 
OR
The Behavioral Effects of Environmental Regimes: Collective-Action vs Social-Practice Models
International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics
2001
, vol. 
1
 
1
(pg. 
9
-
29
)
116
Young
 
OR
Arctic Tipping Points: Governance in Turbulent Times
Ambio
2012
, vol. 
41
 
1
(pg. 
75
-
84
)
117
Zahran
 
S
Samuel
 
DB
Himanshu
 
G
Arnold
 
V
Climate Change Vulnerability and Policy Support
Society and Natural Resources
2006
, vol. 
19
 
9
(pg. 
771
-
89
)
118
Zhao
 
Y
In China, Darwin Meets Marx
New York Times
2004
March
7
119
Zimbardo
 
P
Craig
 
H
Curtis
 
BW
Susan
 
P
David
 
G
Cathy
 
R
Lee
 
R
et al. 
Interpersonal Dynamics in a Simulated Prison
International Journal of Criminology and Penology
1973
, vol. 
1
 
1
(pg. 
69
-
97
)
This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (CC-BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. See http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Supplementary Material